Home / Chroniques / Fragile supply chains: will industries return?
Shot of Sterile Pharmaceutical Manufacturing Laboratory where Scientists in Protective Coverall’s Do Research, Quality Control and Work on the Discovery of new Medicine.
π Economics π Geopolitics π Industry

Fragile supply chains: will industries return?

Isabelle Méjean
Isabelle Méjean
Professor of Economics at Sciences Po

Last spring, inter­na­tion­al sup­ply chains were dis­rupt­ed by the grad­ual spread of the Covid pan­dem­ic across the glob­al econ­o­my. Par­tic­u­lar­ly impact­ed were prod­ucts in high demand to com­bat the virus, rekin­dling the debate about mar­ket glob­al­i­sa­tion. Is it time to bring pro­duc­tion clos­er to home, or will the cur­rent sys­tem have to adapt to new eco­nom­ic risks? For Isabelle Méjean, a researcher at the French Cen­tre for eco­nom­ics and sta­tis­tics (CREST), head of the Eco­nom­ics depart­ment at the Insti­tut Poly­tech­nique de Paris, and Best Young French Econ­o­mist 2020, the prob­lem is strate­gic, rather than economic. 

In your research, you com­bine data from large com­pa­nies to bet­ter under­stand inter­na­tion­al trade flows. What is your objective? 

I use sta­tis­ti­cal data about com­pa­nies, their pro­duc­tion meth­ods and glob­al­i­sa­tion strate­gies to study their micro­eco­nom­ic strate­gies. This can help us bet­ter under­stand cer­tain larg­er-scale, macro­eco­nom­ic phe­nom­e­na. For instance, I study the syn­chro­ni­sa­tion of eco­nom­ic cycles across coun­tries, and how cycli­cal fluc­tu­a­tions in a num­ber of for­eign coun­tries impact the French econ­o­my. In stan­dard macro­eco­nom­ic the­o­ry, cor­re­la­tions between cycles are explained by rel­a­tive price adjust­ments – a rise in activ­i­ty ben­e­fits for­eign com­pa­nies through high­er imports. 

My co-authors and I showed how the glob­al­i­sa­tion strate­gies of a few very large com­pa­nies go a long way towards explain­ing cycle syn­chro­ni­sa­tion. Since dif­fer­ent com­pa­nies devel­op in dif­fer­ent ways, their glob­al­i­sa­tion strate­gies are high­ly var­ied. It is there­fore very dif­fi­cult to prop­er­ly under­stand the aggre­gat­ed phe­nom­e­non with­out delv­ing into the fine sta­tis­ti­cal detail. Hence, we need large swathes of information. 

Of course, we’re not work­ing on the scale of “big data” in the sta­tis­ti­cal sense of the term. But, in order to uncov­er the links between indi­vid­ual deci­sions and macro­eco­nom­ic effects one has to map the entire dis­tri­b­u­tion of com­pa­nies, and this involves a great deal of data. 

Right from the start of 2020, when only Wuhan province was in lock­down, we saw evi­dence of shortages.

Which eco­nom­ic phe­nom­e­non linked to the pan­dem­ic struck you the most? 

Ear­ly on, the pan­dem­ic high­light­ed the inter­de­pen­dence of large inter­na­tion­al com­pa­nies. Right from the start of 2020, when only Wuhan province was in lock­down, we saw evi­dence of short­ages, e.g. in the elec­tron­ics sec­tor, since the world leader in fibre optics oper­ates in the area. At the time, it was dif­fi­cult to fore­see the scale of the pan­dem­ic, and these reper­cus­sions across sup­ply chains appeared to be a unique illus­tra­tion of the lack of resilience to local shocks due to glob­alised production. 

Very quick­ly, the spread of the slow­down in Chi­nese pro­duc­tiv­i­ty through val­ue chains became a sec­ondary con­cern. Espe­cial­ly com­pared to the eco­nom­ic shock­wave sparked by lock­down mea­sures that were imple­ment­ed to man­age the cri­sis across most of the glob­al econ­o­my. But inter­de­pen­dence between com­pa­nies, nation­al­ly and inter­na­tion­al­ly, remains an impor­tant fac­tor in the way our economies func­tion prop­a­gat­ing both neg­a­tive shocks, like the eco­nom­ic lock­down, and pos­i­tive ones, like the recov­ery plans to come. 

Today, the ques­tion is one of resilience. How can we insert shock absorbers into these net­works of com­pa­nies to pre­vent harm­ful domi­no effects? How can we boost nation­al economies, when all coun­tries are faced with the chal­lenges of sub­se­quent waves? Take the Euro­pean auto­mo­bile sec­tor, which is both high­ly frag­ment­ed and inte­grat­ed across Europe: cur­rent­ly, French and Ger­man man­u­fac­tur­ers can­not return to full busi­ness with­out both a resur­gence in demand and a return of activ­i­ty across the entire chain, espe­cial­ly by parts sup­pli­ers in West­ern and East­ern Europe. 

Sup­port­ing demand is an impor­tant part of the recov­ery plan, but sup­ply prob­lems can quick­ly become extreme­ly com­plex in a sec­tor that main­ly pro­duces prod­ucts “just in time” – with low stocks and process opti­mi­sa­tion through­out the sup­ply and pro­duc­tion chains. A fac­to­ry that dis­trib­utes bumpers, for instance, must receive the start­ing mate­r­i­al before they can start the next batch of deliv­er­ies. High­er stocks, which would appear to be the sim­ple answer to dif­fi­cul­ties in sup­ply, are there­fore dif­fi­cult to imple­ment in the short term. In the medi­um term, the ques­tion of inte­grat­ing “just in case” man­age­ment will no doubt arise. 

Will sup­ply chains be off­shored or regionalised?

I don’t believe the mod­el will change. I’m not sure we’re ready to give up the ben­e­fits of glob­al­i­sa­tion, such as an increase in pur­chas­ing pow­er and a diverse range of con­sumer goods. It is believed, for exam­ple, that the increase in trade between France and emerg­ing coun­tries from the mid-1990s to the end of the 2000s gen­er­at­ed gains in pur­chas­ing pow­er of around €1,000 per year per house­hold. That’s hard­ly neg­li­gi­ble, even when these gains are bal­anced against the loss­es – job loss­es, in par­tic­u­lar, which are said to have amount­ed to about 100,000 over the same period. 

Peo­ple are also talk­ing about sov­er­eign­ty. Is this real­ly an eco­nom­ic issue? 

Over the past year, we have heard a lot of talk about “strate­gic” sov­er­eign­ty, or how to reduce our depen­dence on for­eign pro­duc­tion in strate­gic sec­tors, where it con­sti­tutes a risk when geopo­lit­i­cal ten­sions arise. The ques­tion is more about strat­e­gy than eco­nom­ics. And we’re not real­ly talk­ing about actu­al de-glob­al­i­sa­tion. Rather, sub­si­dis­ing the low-prof­it nation­al pro­duc­tion of a small num­ber of tar­get­ed prod­ucts. But where does sov­er­eign­ty end? 

The next cri­sis may require oth­er basic neces­si­ties. I’m afraid we’re real­ly talk­ing about pro­tec­tion­ism, and a deep­er cri­tique of glob­al­i­sa­tion, which is seen as a fac­tor in France’s low growth rate, con­tribut­ing to mass unem­ploy­ment. In my view, this is of far greater con­cern than French depen­dence on a hand­ful of for­eign prod­ucts. But it is, above all, a Euro­pean prob­lem. France’s lack of eco­nom­ic com­pet­i­tive­ness is large­ly man­i­fest in our trade bal­ance deficit with our Euro­pean part­ners. France’s weak mar­ket share in the EU will not be solved by off­shoring low-added-val­ue busi­ness­es. On the con­trary, we need to regain com­pet­i­tive­ness in high tech­nol­o­gy activ­i­ties, the indus­tries of the future. 

Do you think com­pa­nies will change their busi­ness model? 

For them, the cur­rent cri­sis is main­ly a short-term liq­uid­i­ty cri­sis, par­tial­ly off­set by gov­ern­men­tal sup­port. How­ev­er, the eco­nom­ic cri­sis will con­tin­ue, the finan­cial health of com­pa­nies will be severe­ly impact­ed, and invest­ments will slow down. In the short term, I don’t think we can expect com­pa­nies to change their busi­ness mod­el. For them, over­haul­ing sup­ply strate­gies requires large invest­ments which like­ly won’t be on the agen­da any time soon. In the longer term, the suc­ces­sion of crises linked to nat­ur­al dis­as­ters, the pan­dem­ic and polit­i­cal insta­bil­i­ty will prob­a­bly lead them to rethink their glob­al­i­sa­tion strategy. 

Are we see­ing oth­er changes in inter­na­tion­al trade? 

It’s too ear­ly to tell. Trade sta­tis­tics often emerge after the fact. Unlike the 2008 finan­cial cri­sis, where we saw a far greater reduc­tion in trade than in glob­al GDP, we haven’t yet seen a trade col­lapse linked to the pan­dem­ic. In 2020, trade approx­i­mate­ly mir­rored fluc­tu­a­tions in GDP, with a strong reduc­tion in the sec­ond quar­ter, then recov­ery from July onwards. In 2021, GDP will remain at between 2 to 8 points below pre-cri­sis lev­els and it is pos­si­ble that trade will reduce fur­ther, giv­en the per­sis­tent lack of activ­i­ty. Of course, not all coun­tries are impact­ed in the same way. France, with high­ly spe­cialised indus­tries that have been adverse­ly affect­ed by the cri­sis (name­ly, aero­space) will very like­ly expe­ri­ence an increased trade deficit. 

Interview by Clément Boulle

Contributors

Isabelle Méjean

Isabelle Méjean

Professor of Economics at Sciences Po

Isabelle Méjean is a professor of economics at Sciences Po. A member of CEPR since 2017, she has also been a scientific advisor at CEPII and a member of the CESifo research network since January 2025. She was a full professor at Ecole Polytechnique (IP Paris) from 2017 to 2021.

Our world explained with science. Every week, in your inbox.

Get the newsletter